Interesting thoughts. The involvement of Brandenburg and Sweden, I think, is the key issue. Although they seem like plausible Russian partners, neither is in a very good strategic or political situation at the moment.

As I recall, Peter III did try to interest Sweden in his war and offered them Norway, but the Swedes were not in a position to accept. The "Pomeranian War" with Prussia had just come to a ruinous end, leaving Sweden with nothing to show for a huge amount of money spent and thousands of lives lost. The government was broke and facing a crisis of confidence at home. TTL's Pomeranian war was shorter, presumably less costly, and was actually "successful" in a strict sense (the Swedes performed rather poorly but managed to get Usedom and Wollin in the peace treaty), so one could argue that they are in a better position to fight another war. This actually makes war less likely, however, because a "success" in Pomerania will presumably bolster the Hats party then in power, which was pro-French and anti-Russian. Under such leadership, an alliance with Peter intended to expand Russian power in the Baltic seems very unlikely, even if Norway is offered as an inducement.

With Brandenburg, the issue is how long the postwar recovery is going to be. While the electorate remains in the top tier of German states, its core territories have been ravaged, its army is presumably in a shambles, and the state itself is under a minority regency. A Russo-Brandenburger defensive alliance is an eminently sensible idea, but it may be some years before Brandenburg is really prepared to launch another major offensive war. Your scenario seems more plausible a bit further in the future, after Brandenburg recovers its strength, but I'm not sure if Peter has that kind of patience. Additionally, we're making an assumption here that Brandenburg's leadership will continue to be ambitious and aggressive. Frederick's campaign of aggrandizement came to a disastrous and ignoble end ITTL, and his young successor might not be too eager to follow in his footsteps with a campaign of naked conquest against a neighbor. Not every Hohenzollern is Frederick, after all.

As a side note, I think Britain is very unlikely to offer any help to Denmark beyond diplomatic support. Britain's foreign policy is in a severe crisis right now, as with Austria's defection and Prussia's defeat they are left without any significant continental ally. Russia is their great hope for a new friend on the continent (as it was historically), and I suspect the British are unlikely to do anything that might damage prospects for an alliance. Giving material aid to Russia's enemy definitely qualifies.

I think you bring up ssome good arguments.

I agree that if the Swedes are smart they stay out, but Sweden did a lot of stupid things in this period. The potentiak rewards are large, but the the same time it comes at a very high price of having Russia on their western borde.

As for Brandenburg, the potential reward are large for Brandenburg, but it comes at a price. Brandenburg have less than zero claim to any territory controlled by the Danes, so it would send a signal of the new Elector of Brandenburg being a untrustworthy rogue like his uncle. If Russia lose, Brandenburg may not lose any territory (through that's not a entire safe bet, Denmark may take East Frisia and maybe some of the western exclaves), but Brandenburg have ensured a hostile Denmark and Brandenburg without Prussia and Silesia is a smaller power than Denmark, and a much safer target of Danish revenge than Russia.

As for Peter III, I think his survival as Czar would be interesting. The war with Denmark is less dumb than OTL "war", and while I don't think he will win (at least not without Brandenburg joining him) as Danish logistic gives them an edge, he could very well survive and maybe even learn from it. Honestly I could see him starting the war, winning and/or losing a few battles, only to have to deal with a coup attempt at home and maybe surviving it. This force him to make a fast and humilating peace with Denmark, where Denmark buy Holstein-Gottorp (so that it look less humilating) and he plan for an later reconquest, when he have established control at home (which end up taking most of the rest of his life).

Denmark here is forced out of its position of neutrality simply because of fear of Russia, at the same time Crown Prince Christian VII of Denmark are born after the POD which mean his madness is butterflied away. The Hessian princes still end up in Denmark (the reason for them ending up in Denmark is unlikley to chane). The lack of madness again means a later marriage marriage for the crown prince (his sister likely marry much as they did in OTL), the hostility to Russia likely mean no British marriage for the prince, a interesting alternative marriage would instead be Princess Sophie Albertina of Sweden (or technical her hypothetical doppelganger who share the same name), which would bind Denmark and Sweden closer, which Denmark would have interest in with a hostile Russia.
 
A few thoughts more. If Denmark comes out of the conflict with Russia with more or less the result I envisioned. We can expect a few things. Denmark is like I said forced out of neutrality. Of course that doesn't mean that Denmark will necessary develop a alliance with France or UK. It in fact will likely be forced to build it own mini-alliance to counter the Russians. Here the fact that Christian VII is sane help a lot, especially because even if the military success may give Frederik V a few more years, he will still die relative young. I think we can expect this doppelganger to be above average intelligence, while Christian was a lunatic, he was intelligent and all his full sibling was also intelligent, they likely inherite this from their mother rather than their drunken idiot of a father (made more obvious by the fact their half sibling from their father's second marriage was on the slow side). I expect the experience of his father drinking himself to death will keep Christian VII less likely to become a alcoholic or at least keep him mostly functioning. I expect he will be reform-minded, outside Christian VI few Danish kings was truly reactionary under absolutism (and even Christian VI tried to establish universal education). I expect to see agricultural, education and military reforms under Christian VII. The agricultural reforms will be the most interesting, because following the reforms in OTL, we saw a major population boom, which will hit earlier here and create 20-30 years down the road a larger labor expansion, at the same time as Denmark saw a several decades long economic boom in OTL (which to large extent was result of the ARW).

The Danish mini alliance will likely primarily be made up of the Hessian, Mecklenburgian and the lesser Welfian states. With Brandenburg broken Denmark will be a safe actor for these states to ally with, especially as the Danes doesn't care to challenge the emperor and the emperor and the French de facto support Denmark as counter to Russian influence in the Baltic. Denmark will likely also try it best to pull the Saxons, Brandenburgians and Swedes into Danish orbit likely with mixed or limited success.

Denmark will be more active abroad, Corsica here is a perfect partner. We will likely see the Danish navy try to cut its teeth on the Barbary States. Denmark is also likely to attempt a few colonial adventures. I think that they have the possession they "want" in the West Indies and India. Which means they will look elsewhere, but likely a place where they don't challenge UK, France, Spain or Netherlands. A naval base on Corsica will be interesting, especially as the Danes position as neutral toward UK, Austria and France make such a base harmless for them.
 
Sowing the Seeds
Sowing the Seeds


7Gdj36V.png

A basket of Corsican citrons


Despite King Theodore’s great interest in promoting trade, the Corsican economy was overwhelmingly a rural economy - and not a very advanced rural economy at that. The crops, tools, and methods used by the Corsican farmer had remained virtually unchanged for centuries. A new generation of Corsican notables, raised in a free state and increasingly aware of the advances being made in “enlightened” Europe, set their minds to the task of bringing Corsican agriculture - and thus Corsica - into the modern age.

Corsican “ignorance” of modern crops and techniques had shocked Henri Léonard Bertin, who had famously complained in the 1750s that the Corsicans “know nothing except how to fire a musket.” Bertin, however, was sometimes too quick to blame the Corsicans for their own poverty. He had railed against the “irrational” crop selection of the peasants, who often planted crops in unsuitable soils and climes, but the rugged terrain and lack of roads forced villages to make subpar choices: If you cannot reliably import grain you must grow your own, no matter how unfavorable the conditions are for wheat. Isolated from any “national” market, let alone international trade, most villages could not grow cash crops even if they had possessed the means and expertise.

Bertin also observed many social and legal obstacles to prosperity, some of which have already been mentioned. The need for diverse holdings and the practice of partible inheritance led to landholdings often being small and scattered.[1] Land rights were often complex, with multiple owners and discrete shares of property (a room in a house, one part of an irrigation system, or even a branch of a chestnut tree). Traditional grazing rights on stubble and fallow fields interfered with enclosure, the planting of “un-grazable” crops (like the potato), and the use of year-round crop rotation.

The dull business of land reform was never one of Theodore’s favorite subjects, but he did issue some constructive edicts in the 1750s. The division of land parcels below a certain size was prohibited, and the threshold was revised upwards in later years. Land dowries were banned, and a man’s eldest married son (or eldest son, if none were married) was declared his sole legal heir if he died intestate. A registrar’s office was established to record wills and deeds, and efforts were made to send advocates and notaries to rural communities to help draft these documents. More transformative reforms, however, had to wait for the new generation of “enlightened” Corsican leaders. Secretary Pasquale Paoli and his fellow “Asphodelians” in the post-1764 government considered land reform to be a priority. Like the proponents of enclosure in England, they argued that village commons and open fields were inefficient and discouraged the adoption of modern techniques and methods. They drafted proposals to allow farmers to enclose their own land and to buy out or dissolve competing use rights, to allow villages to enclose and privatize their own corporate commons, to encourage the cultivation and enclosure of “wastelands," and to offer incentives for farmers to adopt new crops and methods.

The ultimate objective of the enlightened reformers, however, was radically different from that of the English gentry. The English were moving inexorably towards “landlord capitalism,” in which large, consolidated estates were worked by wage labor. To this end it was necessary to dispossess the peasantry not only from the commons but their own smallholdings, in order to grow the great estates and create a “free but landless peasantry” which was entirely dependent upon wages. But the Corsican reformers had no desire to create “great estates,” nor were they in favor of wage labor or wholesale dispossession. On the contrary, they envisioned enclosure as strengthening the landholding peasantry, as the privatization of common land would presumably allow more peasants to ascend to the ranks of proprietari, those who subsisted wholly off their own property. While this might dispossess poorer peasants who were dependent on the commons, the reformers argued that this problem would be solved by the cultivation of more acres and increased productivity from the new techniques that land reform would enable.[2]

Their arguments were not purely economic. Many asfodelati saw enclosure as a means to undermine the power of the gigliati, their political rivals, believing that a peasantry which was more secure in its own property would be less vulnerable to the influence and encroachments of the estate-owning sgio. Reformers pointed out that a majority of vendetta killings involved disputes over land or inheritance, and claimed that enclosure, exclusive fee-simple ownership, and well-regulated inheritance laws would end the vendetta as an institution. More broadly, reformers argued that free proprietorship would ensure the civic morality of the people, as the free, independent, patriotic proprietario was the only sure foundation of Corsican “democracy” and national defense.

Despite this enthusiasm, Paoli and his allies soon became discouraged by a lack of support from the crown. The Corsican government did not have effective legislative powers, which made them dependent upon the king’s edicts for real reform. Theodore, however, was always a bit nervous about making any drastic moves that might cost him his popularity among the peasantry. Taking on the Church was quite radical enough without also undertaking the Herculean task of completely transforming rural life. The king’s own idea of agricultural development did not involve peasant land reform so much as the encouragement of cash crops grown for export.

Corsican olives had attracted the kingdom’s first significant foreign backer, the Dutch syndicate later known as the Nederlands-Corsicaanse Compagnie (NCC), which established a “factory” at Isola Rossa in the 1750s for the barreling and export of oil. The early years after independence had been promising, but the Company’s presence had been little appreciated by the French. After the Convention of Ajaccio the French seized control of Isola Rossa and effectively shut down the NCC’s operations. The Company regained control of its factory in 1760, but business never resumed. A plunge in grain prices after the Four Years’ War ruined a number of over-leveraged bankers and speculators and led to a general banking crisis in Amsterdam. One of the most spectacular collapses involved the firm of Leendert de Neufville, an NCC shareholder whose father Pieter de Neufville had been one of the original founders of the Syndicate. For the NCC, whose books were already deep in the red, this disaster proved to be the final straw. The Company was dissolved in 1762 and its remaining assets in Corsica were acquired by the crown. Individual Dutch merchants would continue to buy oil in Corsica but they enjoyed no special favor, and their share of this trade grew ever smaller in comparison to the activity of British, French, and Danish merchants.


RdTO4Fl.png

Corsican women gathering olives near Isola Rossa, early 20th century


In an unfortunate twist for the NCC, the years following the Company’s collapse saw the beginning of a sustained rise in olive oil prices across Europe. Rising prices in the late 1760s can be linked to the 1764-67 famine in Naples, a major oil producer, but demand was also growing over the long term as a consequence of a new phenomenon: the Industrial Revolution. The steam engines and mechanical looms beginning to appear in Britain could not function without lubrication, and olive oil was considered to be the best industrial lubricant available. Corsican olive oil, however, was not favored for this purpose - it wasn’t good enough.

The olive oil produced in Corsica was of a low grade marked by relatively high acidity. This was perfectly suitable for common consumption and for soapmaking, which had been the NCC’s main use for Corsican oil. Low-acidity oil, however - known as olio fino or “virgin” olive oil - worked better as a lubricant, burned more efficiently in lamps, lasted much longer before turning rancid, and was preferred at the tables of the wealthy. Olio fino was thus in great demand, and could command up to twice the price of common oil. To make olio fino, however, it was necessary to prune the trees regularly and pick olives earlier, when they were harder and less ripe. These practices were largely foreign to Corsica, and crushing unripe olives required new and stronger milling machines and presses. Although the island had many streams capable of powering mills, very few Corsicans had the capital or knowledge to construct and operate the required marchinery.[3] Some screw presses were introduced into the Balagna in the 1760s, but milling technology still lagged well behind the continent and marketable olio fino comprised a negligible fraction of Corsican output.

Oil and wine continued to be the isle’s most important agricultural exports, but new crops also began to make an appearance. Theodore had conceived the “crown estates” as not merely a source of revenue for himself and his household, but a “laboratory” in which new and beneficial plants could be tested and cultivated. The director of this research was Salvadore Ginestra, a Roman-educated botanist and Theodore’s minister of agriculture. Although Ginestra experimented with a number of different crops, his most promising experiments in the 1760s involved tobacco. Tobacco, in fact, had been grown on Corsica since the late 16th century and was still widely cultivated; peasants sowed their tobacco in empty livestock pens during spring (as the soil there came pre-fertilized), harvested the leaves in August, and dried them in open air. The variety they planted, however, was Nicotiana rustica, which was a hardy variety but produced a strong, harsh smoke. This was good enough for the pipes of the peasants, but there was no export market for N. rustica. Sophisticated tobacco consumers preferred the milder and smoother Nicotiana tabacum.

Ginestra managed to obtain N. tabacum seeds from France, and after several false starts he eventually succeeded in establishing tobacco farms in in western Corsica at Cargese (near the former Greek colony of Paomia) and Campo dell'Oro at the mouth of the Gravona. In the 1770s N. tabacum cultivation was also introduced to the upper Tavignano, east of Corti. The growing and production process proved challenging; N. tabacum was a temperamental crop requiring intensive labor and large amounts of fertilizer, and Ginestra’s plantations were necessarily limited in scale. Corsica did not export any significant quantity of tobacco in the 1760s, but Ginestra's experimental farms were the start of a very successful venture. Within just a few decades tobacco would become one of Corsica’s primary exports, and by the end of the century Ajaccio would be almost as well known for fine cigars as for coral beads.

The potato, a fellow nightshade, was also introduced to Corsica in this period. The potato had existed in Italy for 200 years, but it had never caught on owing mainly to the conservatism of the peasantry and the feudal society they lived in. The Neapolitan famine of 1764 re-ignited Italian interest in this New World crop, although it must be conceded that this interest was mainly confined to the enlightened literati and had little immediate effect on Italian farmers. Potatoes in Corsica were only marginally more successful. Ginestra purchased a load of potatoes from English traders in 1764 and established a few plots, and in 1768 Theodore issued a famous “potato edict” in which he required all tenants on crown land, as well as all holders of estates over a certain size, to grow a potato patch using seed potatoes from the crown estates.

Trying to establish potato culture by fiat did not turn out very well. Corsican farmers knew nothing about potato cultivation - or potato consumption, for that matter. Many gave up rather quickly, claiming that their land was unsuitable, and the edict was largely repealed after Theodore’s death. The potato also suffered from a problem of perception, for even Ginestra did not consider the potato (which he called a tartufo, “truffle”) as a field crop. In his opinion it was a garden crop that was best used as a “flour extender,” not a staple in its own right. Thus, while small-scale potato cultivation did continue in the 1770s (mainly in the north and east), it remained largely restricted to garden plots alongside crops like beans and lettuce and did not catch on among the wider peasantry.

Alongside new plants, this period also saw the revival of old crops with new and potentially lucrative applications. Chief among these was the citron, known locally as the alimea. The Corsican citron, grown largely in Capo Corso and the vicinity of Bastia, was a particularly sweet variety of the fruit and was highly regarded for the production of succade (candied peel) and jam. Corsica had long been one of the major producers of citrons and the fruit had been an important export in the Genoese period, but its production had been disrupted by the Revolution and the ensuing emigration of Genoese proprietors in Capo Corso. Traditionally, citrons had been shipped whole to Genoa where they were pulped and brined in preparation for export, and these methods and facilities had to be established from scratch in post-independence Corsica. Nevertheless, by the 1760s citron exports were booming - thanks, in large part, to the Jews.


Rf7a2Zh.png

An early 18th century silver etrog box from Germany


Known as the etrog or esrog in Hebrew, the citron had great ritual and symbolic importance in Judaism. In particular, a fresh etrog was a component of the ritual feast of Sukkot. In the 16th century, rabbinical authorities ruled that only ungrafted citrons could be used for religious purposes, which ruled out most citrons from Italy and Spain where the fruit trees were typically grafted to improve their hardiness. For once, Corsica’s lack of agricultural sophistication actually became an advantage, as by the 18th century it was one of the few places in Europe where ungrafted citrons were still produced. As citrons could not be grown in the colder climates of central and northern Europe, Ashkenazi communities were particularly dependent on the Yanover Etrog (“Genoa citron,” so called because it was exported from Genoa), as well as etrogim from Apulia and Ottoman Greece.

As citron production recovered and news of Theodore’s “emancipation” spread, buying a Corsican etrog was seen by many Ashkenazim as not only the fulfillment of a ritual duty but an act of support for Theodoran tolerance, the Judeo-Corsican community, and Jewish emancipation more generally. Various rabbis from central Europe in the late 18th century not only affirmed the suitability of Corsican etrogim, but declared that they were preferred for ritual use over citrons imported from other nations. For prosperous Ashkenazi families, obtaining a Corsican etrog for Sukkot was simultaneously a symbol of status, solidarity, and piety. Whole, ungrafted Corsican citrons were exported as far as Poland and Russia, where the treasured fruits were carefully kept in decorative wooden or silver boxes by families who had never even seen a citron tree.[4] This trade was very lucrative for Corsican citron growers, especially because the Jews wanted their citrons whole, which meant that their product could be sold immediately at a good price without any of the processing or brining that was normally necessary for citron export.[5]

Another other old crop used in a new way was mulberry, which had been introduced to the island by the Genoese in the 16th century alongside the chestnut. Up to this point the Corsicans had grown the mulberry mainly for fruit and fodder (as the leaves could be fed to animals), but Theodore had realized from the very beginning of his reign that Corsican mulberry trees were no different than those grown on mainland Italy to feed silkworms. Building a Corsican silk industry had long been one of his aspirations, but it was not until the 1760s that he was able to find the capital and expertise to make it a reality.

A key figure in this enterprise was the Tuscan radical Filippo Mazzei, a physician turned merchant who sailed to London in 1756 and fell in love with “English liberty.” He had worked there as a language teacher and befriended Ambassador Paoli. Upon returning home, however, he was condemned by the Pisan Inquisition for attempting to import an “immense quantity of banned books” and had to flee Tuscany. He took refuge in Corsica, where his friend Paoli was now Secretary of State, and became convinced that the Corsican Kingdom was the “sole redoubt” of liberty and enlightenment in Italy. Although the Corsican government was no British parliamentary monarchy, there was no oppressive feudal order and censorship was nonexistent. He visited Rousseau, was inducted into the Order of the Asphodel, and personally offered his services to King Theodore.


2qmwFif.png

Diagram of a Piedmontese reeling machine, c. 1750


In 1766 Mazzei managed to smuggle live cocoons out of Lucca which were successfully established at a royal mulberry orchard near Oletta. In that year Theodore chartered the Royal Silk Company (Compagnia Reale di Seta), a semi-autonomous royal corporation created to pool private investment in Corsican silk production. Funding was secured from Corsican, Jewish, and particularly English investors. The British silk industry was facing a crisis of supply, and new sources of good quality raw silk were eagerly sought after.[6] The Company hired a number of Piedmontese experts while Mazzei obtained British-made reeling machines. These machines were set up in a “filature” (a facility for silk reeling) at Oletta, and a more advanced water-powered reeling mill was built at Rutali in 1770. A London newspaper claimed in 1769 that the new Corsican silkworms were “healthy and vigorous” and that the quality of Corsican silk was “as fine as, if not superior to” Piedmontese silk. This must be taken with a grain of salt - and whatever the quality, the quantity produced in the Nebbio were very modest - but clearly Corsica was capable of making a decent and marketable product.

Although clearly not all of his ideas had met with wild success, Theodore regarded his agricultural export policy in the 1760s with considerable pride. Corsica’s presence in international trade was growing and Corsican ports were busier than they had ever been under the stultifying rule of the Genoese. Most Corsicans, however, remained distant from these new developments. The commercial production of oil, wine, citrons, tobacco, and silk was concentrated mainly in the northern plains, Capo Corso, and the vicinity of Ajaccio. Although the rural economy of the interior certainly benefited from the prolonged peace and export revenues did fund projects in the interior (particularly roads), there was a growing sense that most Corsicans were being left behind. This perception only made the demands of the reformers more urgent. A reckoning was coming - but it would not be on Theodore’s watch.


Footnotes
[1] The equal division of property between sons is often held up as the Corsican norm, but in practice this was far from absolute. Corsican families were not ignorant of the problems of infinitely dividing the family patrimony; a common saying in the Niolo was “parte richessa, torna poverta" (part the wealth and poverty follows). As such, many farmers circumvented or simply ignored this custom to concentrate the wealth in the hands of a single married son (usually, but not always, the eldest). Other sons might continue to live with the family and remain unmarried (known as fa a ziu, “to act as an uncle”) or might be encouraged to emigrate, which was historically a major source of Corsican mercenaries. In general, the poorer a family was, the more likely they were to practice impartible inheritance. Thus, far from resenting the Theodoran move towards single-heir inheritance as a violation of custom, many peasant families welcomed it as codifying and strengthening a practice which was essential to their survival.
[2] Notably, the reformers were not against all commons. They were perfectly fine with maintaining most coastal lowlands as commons for seasonal farming and grazing, as due to endemic malaria much of this land could not be permanently cultivated anyway. To enclose these lands would be a virtual declaration of war upon all the shepherds in Corsica, a prospect which nobody relished.
[3] There was also an incentive problem. In Corsica, mills were generally leased to tenants by their owners. The amount of the lease was the same regardless of how many olives the tenant milled or how much oil they yielded, so mill owners gained nothing from investing in new technology to increase efficiency or enhance the quality of oil produced.
[4] Empress Maria Theresa famously imposed an annual tax of 40,000 florins on the Jews of Bohemia for the right to import citrons, knowing full well what they would pay dearly to procure them.
[5] Some of the earliest Jewish settlement in Bastia was associated with the citron trade. While the citrons themselves were grown by gentile Corsicans, it was useful to have a few resident Jewish merchants who could verify the ungrafted nature of the plants and assist foreign buyers with arranging purchases.
[6] The British considered Italian silk to be the highest quality, but it was expensive and sometimes restricted; the King of Sardinia had banned all raw silk exports to protect his domestic silk weavers. Persian and Indian silk was cheaper, but of mediocre quality. In their quest for alternatives the British had attempted to establish sericulture in Georgia and South Carolina, but it failed to catch on. The main problem was slavery, as silk production required a skilled workforce and simply could not compete with the per-acre profit margins of slave-harvested cash crops like indigo and rice.
 
Last edited:
That was fascinating alternative crops is something I've learned a lot about from the various Lands of Red & Gold inspired timelines and good to see it here as well.
 
That was fascinating alternative crops is something I've learned a lot about from the various Lands of Red & Gold inspired timelines and good to see it here as well.

Well, all of these crops did exist on Corsica historically. Tobacco was a significant export in the 19th century, and there seems to have been a short period when silk was grown. Antoine Valery recorded in 1837 that some good silk was produced in Capo Corso, although he noted that it was "one of the numerous sources of wealth and prosperity neglected in the island." Corsican sericulture doesn't seem to have gone anywhere. "Neglect" is basically the story of post-annexation Corsican agriculture IOTL, exacerbated by the negative effects of union which denied Corsican goods any sort of protection from French goods.

After the French annexation a lot of proposals were floated regarding possible Corsican crops - sugar, cotton, madder, indigo, pineapple - which seem rather dubious to me. Thus far, I've chosen what I consider to be a pretty conservative path: Crops which were actually grown on Corsica, but introduced earlier and with more diligence than the French government ever attempted.
 
Last edited:
I wonder whether the citron will remain the only example of Corsican agricultural traditionality proving advantageous, too...

Yeah, that bit was my favorite. Always love the bits of TLs that read like out of left field asspulls but are entirely historical.

On the subject of citrons here in Korea people take citrons and chop them up and preserve them in a sweet syrup (traditionally honey was used, these days more often corn syrup etc.) and then spoon in some sweet citron goo in with hot water as "citron tea" (yuja cha). It's really good actually. Fermented some one time and I liked that better than hard lemonade once I'd filtered out the goo, could work as a flavoring for some local rotgut.

1.-Yuja-Tea-Yuzu-tea-500x500.jpg


For other low tech export industries would dried fish or other seafood be possible? Dried fish as a huge amount of protein per gram and species with low fat meat keep well so could work out. Dried fish was a big export industry for early America .
 
Last edited:
Once again, you display an amazing amount of knowledge in your update. :eek: to the point of knowing the actual quality of Corsican olive oil compared to Napolitan one, the amount and locations of mills on the island, the possible export outlets for citron in Jewish communities, the varieties of tobacco cultivated in some villages...
I can't imagine the amount of research you go through for writing this timeline, you're probably now more expert on XVIII th century Corsica than anyone in the world ! (and as far as I have understood, without speaking either French or Italian)
You are probably the prototype of the perfect AH writer, getting an incredibly extensive knowledge on your topic, researching the effects on the rest of the world, weighing plausibilities, ...
I admire you and your work. Please keep going the pleasure ! 🤩
 
Seconding on the dried fish. Corsica seems to be in a good place to export such things, unless all the Mediterranean countries have a better process of exporting dried seafood.
 
Seconding on the dried fish. Corsica seems to be in a good place to export such things, unless all the Mediterranean countries have a better process of exporting dried seafood.

Just not sure which species of fish they can catch in large numbers. Atlantic cod is pretty much perfect for drying due to the low fat content means it keeps very well.

Same in Korea where Pacific cod is a very common fish for drying. In the old days farms would have a bunch of dried cod hanging on the walls. You could tell it was a bad year if the dried cod was getting thin.

The Atlantic cod fisheries are still going strong at this point so that's some strong competition but cheap protein that doesn't rot easily could still find a market.
 
Just not sure which species of fish they can catch in large numbers. Atlantic cod is pretty much perfect for drying due to the low fat content means it keeps very well.

Same in Korea where Pacific cod is a very common fish for drying. In the old days farms would have a bunch of dried cod hanging on the walls. You could tell it was a bad year if the dried cod was getting thin.

The Atlantic cod fisheries are still going strong at this point so that's some strong competition but cheap protein that doesn't rot easily could still find a market.
Cod is found in the Med, but I think Corsican waters are more bountiful in tuna - which I suspect is less effectively dried.
 

formion

Banned
Cod is found in the Med, but I think Corsican waters are more bountiful in tuna - which I suspect is less effectively dried.
That is a common misconception. What mediterranean fishermen call cod, is actually hake. Tuna is far more abundant in western Sicily. I doubt Corsica can have a major tuna fishery.

As the author stated many times, Corsica has a lot of corals. In the Med it means one thing: Sparidae family fish. King Theodore can feast on delicious dentex and red sea bream. Corsica is also a decent place for scorpaena, excellent for soup. However, you can have an export industry of those fish only after refrigeration arrives. The only potentially valuable fish are sardines, but I doubt the fishery will amount for much. We should remember, the Med is not as rich as North Atlantic.

What is also worth mentioning is the fact that in OTL, major salt pans were developed in Porto Vecchio after 1795.
 
Sardines, anchovies, sea bream, and red mullet are common in the area and often appear in modern Corsican cuisine. Yet while there are some fishing communities in Corsica proper (mainly in Ajaccio, Bastia, and Capo Corso), the historical concentration of settlement in the interior meant that fishing was never a major economic activity.

A notable exception is the island of Capraia, which is located in a major anchovy fishery. Exporting salted and pickled anchovies to Genoa, Livorno, and other regional ports was the basis of Capraia's economy and occupied most of the island's approximately 1,000-1,500 residents.
 
Very interesting. Corsican lemons shipped all across Europe and even into Russia for Jewish ceremonies, and that being OTL if perhaps less prevalent, is a very interesting idea. So too is the concept of Corsican silk becoming fashionable in the UK. It's also fascinating to think of the potential knock on effects and outside persception of land enclosures with the objective of building up and stabilizing a class of land-owning freemen.

Also, we all know what the younger-sons-becoming-mercenaries will lead to. There will be a famous Corsican mercenary company led by a grandson of dear old Giuseppe Maria di Buonaparte poking around somewhere at some point. Perhaps they will imitate King Theodore in taking over a revolt somewhere else.

As for King Theodore coming to the end of his reign - He can rest easy. Few men have taken a rebellious province of a foreign state, took over the revolution, beat a great power who wandered in for a quick land-grab, created a stable nation from the rebelling province and, most spectacularly and rarely, made it clearly a much better place to live.
 
Looks like the most important thing that could happen for Corsican development is anti-malarial measures.

Anchovies can also be dried instead of brined, dried anchovies are popular in Korea and high in calcium since they're small enough to be eaten whole. Not sure anyone in Europe would want dried anchovies though.

For the citron, there must be a market for some kind of citron-flavored booze or marmalade or hot drink, that shit is delicous.
 

formion

Banned
Not sure anyone in Europe would want dried anchovies though.
I wouldnt think so. Dried fish is a rather alien concept in the Med. Brined or salted were the two methods for preservation. E.g you marinate anchovies in salt and wine vinegar and then you preserve the fillets in oil.
 

formion

Banned
For the citron, there must be a market for some kind of citron-flavored booze or marmalade or hot drink, that shit is delicous.
Mediterranean people traditionally made citron marmelade. At least in Greece, citrons are also used to make liqueur. The problem with exporting citron products and not just the fruits, is that you need great quantities of expensive imported sugar.
 
I wouldnt think so. Dried fish is a rather alien concept in the Med. Brined or salted were the two methods for preservation. E.g you marinate anchovies in salt and wine vinegar and then you preserve the fillets in oil.
Dried cod was very popular in Venice, where it is still a prominent part of local cuisine. I think it was imported Atlantic cod, though.
 
Last edited:
Top